Economics (of Dating) 101: Talk is Cheap

3:49 AM

A series where I attempt to explain basic economic principles through the global dating scene. (Note: imported from previous blog)

Q: In college, I used to wait two days before replying someone I was interested in. But now I have bills to pay, corporate ladders to climb...you know, these games are getting pretty exhausting. Why can't we just be direct with one another?

Actually, that's something I've been pondering as well. Why is it so hard for two human beings to be completely honest and upfront with each other? Sure, there's the so-called "thrill of the chase," but shouldn't we have evolved enough to figure out more efficient ways of courting?

To explain further: Communication essentially involves a sender transmitting a message to a receiver. In the 21st century, when we send a text message to someone, it's assumed that our service provider will successfully and accurately transmit that message to the receiver. But it seems that the evolution of human interaction has not matched the exponential growth of satellite communications. When we humans communicate, elements such as "pride" and "selfishness" create noise in the channel, distorting our true intents into confusing mixed messages.

For those who like diagrams--in a perfectly efficient world, dating would look like this:

So simple. So truthful. But alas, so far removed from the realities of our time!

Instead, modern day dating seems to be more like this:

 **Note: I've learned that this type of message falls under the category of "negging"

Or, it might also look like this:

Q: Those are definitely accurate portrayals, but my question still stands--isn't it easier to just tell each other the truth then?

Well, from an economic perspective, sometimes people really have no incentive to tell the truth. I know that's a depressing answer, but let's try to break it down to understand why.

In game theory, cheap talk is a type of communication where sending and receiving messages is:
  • costless (in terms of both time & money)
  • non-binding
  • unverifiable
Sounds a bit familiar, doesn't it? Indeed, society and technology have progressed such that there are now multiple dating channels where one can communicate with no/low cost and with no commitment:
  • free online dating apps
  • social media
  • bars
  • etc., etc. 
More specifically, because there is no obligation to see or talk to each other again in most of these settings, each party will choose the action that maximizes their short-term gain. But because they both know this of each other, they are less likely to believe 100% of what the other party says. This leads to situations where both parties can harmlessly flirt with each other but no "action" is taken. For example, why would Justin ask Selena out on an actual date if there's a good chance that she was only flirting for her own short-term satisfaction?

That's cheap talk in a nutshell---when communication is costless/non-binding, most "messages" sent are uninformative and do not affect outcomes. Therefore, people can lie about their true nature/intentions without incurring any negative payoffs.

Q: Uh...too many words--where are my graphs?

Unbelievable...fine, let's try to visualize the decision-making process of a player:
As you can see, if Justin Bieber's true nature is that of a playboy, he can either flirt with Selena (and lie about his true nature) or be an honest man and not hurt her feelings. His two possible expected payoffs would be:
  • Honest: 0
  • Dishonest: (50%)*(0) + (50%)*(5) = 2.5
    • Note: here he assumes there's a 50% chance Selena will respond positively to flirting
Conclusion: Justin has zero incentive to be honest! The rules of game theory and probability have thus concluded that in a noncommittal environment, a player will always play.

And what about our dearest Selena? Given that Justin will always flirt, her optimal strategy here is to not fall for Justin's tricks. She can either ignore him completely or harmlessly flirt back with no expectations, but she definitely should not walk down the "fall for Justin" path.

Q: That's horrifying...is there any scenario where dishonesty and distrust are not optimal strategies?

Oh yes, let me try to end on a more positive note. As I mentioned before, in some cases people do have incentive to tell the truth! Here's an example:
If Justin really does like Selena, his best strategy is to follow his true intentions and flirt with Selena, due to the expected payoffs below:
  • Inaction: 0
  • Action: (50%)*(5)+(50%)*(-2) = 1.5 -----> still a higher payoff than not trying
    • Note: He's still assuming a 50% probability of reciprocation. Also, I gave Justin a -2 rejection payoff as opposed to a -5 (that I gave Selena previously) because Selena never led him on/gave him false hope in this case!
However, a problem arises--Selena will benefit if she falls for a Justin who truly likes her. But based on her past experiences with players, she also knows that it's risky to always fall for whoever flirts with her. How can sincere Justin differentiate himself from all the other players to ensure Selena always responds positively to his flirting?

 Economics has provided a couple solutions to this problem:
  • Sign a contract: Just to clarify, I'm not referring to 50 Shades of Grey-type contracts. I mean that Justin should signal commitment to Selena through "binding actions" such as proposing a date and eventually even referring to her as his "girlfriend" or "significant other." These acts of commitment are easy for Justin to do if he truly likes Selena, but much more costly for the players to do as it requires them to give up other opportunities. Contract theory is probably why some people insist that "if you like it then you better put a ring on it"--having a binding contract not only sends a positive signal to the receiver and facilitates trust, it also gives both parties more incentive to act in each other's interests. 
  • Send costly signals: Instead of communicating through flirting, which is low cost and thus easy to disregard, Justin should also send indirect, costly signals to indicate his interest more effectively. Examples of costly signaling include (but are not limited to) dressing up in "honest", "nice guy" attire, buying her gifts, writing her poetry, possessing jobs, degrees and habits conventionally regarded as "dependable" and "trustworthy." Since these signals require more effort than just talking or messaging, they might help to reassure Selena that Justin is being serious. Of course, I would not recommend the costly signaling seen in the 1997 film Titanic, where Jack signaled his love for and commitment to Rose by giving up his life.  
    • (Yes, I'm on team "there was totally space on that raft") 

 Q: Wow, who knew there was so much theory behind this silly game of dating?

Exactly! Dating is a complex web of signals, action, and reaction, where participants try their best to optimize their choices at each step based on prior experiences and beliefs. With this in mind, perhaps we should not totally blame the more "selfish" and "heartless" participants, and instead think about how we can create a better dating ecosystem where dishonesty is not an optimal strategy.

Q: Hold on, are you saying what I think you're saying? Are you basically saying...don't hate the player, hate the game? 

 ........you caught me there. I definitely could've explained this whole concept in that one line....

You Might Also Like

0 comments